Judicial Reforms,First Step towards Knowledge Management?

others 1246 views 2 replies
Do You agree that Judicial Reforms is First steps towards Knowledge Management? if Yes,Why? Let's discuss as many of us feel that Jungle of Irrelevant,Illogicals Acts Rules.............etc Contributing Negative Growth for INDIA.
Replies (2)
25 May 2007 - The blurb on the back-cover begins with a reference to the 'vulnerability of the poor', but the collection of essays in Judicial Reforms in India: Issues and Aspects restricts itself to discussing judicial reform in the context of economic growth - focussing on protection of property and contract enforcement. The editors, Arnab Kumar Hazra and Bibek Debroy too begin their introduction by asserting the belated recognition of legal reforms as a critical ingredient of economic reforms; their reference to poverty is a few paragraphs later: "A balanced swift, affordable (accessible) and fair justice delivery system besides promoting law and order, aids in the development of markets, investments, including foreign direct investments, and economic growth, and therefore helps in poverty reduction" (emphasis added). This reliance on the trickle-down approach lies at the centre of the collection of essays explaining many of its arguments, omissions and conclusions. In fact while later in the introduction the editors claim that they do not wish to enter into the debate on "whether law reform should facilitate market transactions, or whether the emphasis should be on promoting good governance and alleviating poverty", the focus of the essays themselves leaves little doubt about their position in this debate. For one, Bibek Debroy and Laveesh Bhandari's essay is titled 'Legal Structure and Economic Freedom of States in India' and is a classic neo-liberal plea for minimal government interference and regulation of commerce. Unsurprisingly it asserts that labour law has been unduly favouring rights of workers over business, and supports increasing of unorganised labour force to enable "hire and fire in order to maximise efficiency of workforce and profits", as also Special Economic Zones. It is this specific understanding of reform, often couched in the language of 'rule of law' and 'access to justice' that is deeply problematic. When the judicial reform process and access to justice is only for the benefit of corporations and commerce and not the people, access to justice is merely shorthand for safer access to markets, and the rule of law cannot but be seen as the "rule of capital" (Baxi, 2006). The fact that 'good governance' machinery is used to erode rights of persons and communities who come in the path of market expansion and economic growth leads one to agree with Upendra Baxi that such a reading of 'access to justice' is part of the problem, and not the solution. Justice, more than mere access Over half a decade ago the move in Canada was towards promoting justice rather than merely enabling better access to the legal system. (Hughes and Mossman: 2001). Unfortunately this collection of essays still considers access to the courts as the main task at hand. Such an approach assumes the courts to be a neutral terrain where class, caste, religion, gender and other similar factors play no role whatsoever. Justice Bhuraka's essay, 'Contemporary Views on Access to Justice in India' further restricts the notion of access to justice only to the independence of the judiciary proceeding thereafter to a general coverage on the use of information and communication technology in the courts, alternate dispute resolution (ADR) and financial autonomy for the courts. This blinkered approach ignores other 'contemporary' concerns around the possibility and quality of justice, especially those raised by dalit rights, women's rights activists or by the various social movements in the country (PCJA&JR 2007). Instead of recognising such concerns, the author observes that the judiciary "commands the respect of the people of India" and is "held in high esteem" in the developing and developed countries while the editors too assert that the legal system is regarded to be fair. In fact one (seemingly mandatory) essay titled Justice and the Poor by Videh Upadhyay aside, the collection of essays is startlingly silent on crucial issues that relate to the vast majority of citizens. The nuts and bolts of reforms For readers who can however look beyond such fundamental political positions, the collection offers a number of essays that examine the nuts and bolts of judicial reforms; which the editors distinguish from statutory law reform (changes required in legislation) and administrative law reform (changes required in rules, regulations, orders and instructions). However even here, the ambit of judicial reform is restricted to a discussion only on reduction of the backlog of pending cases and tackling incoming cases more efficiently. Read within this limited sphere, some of the essays may be useful to those working specifically on reducing backlogs in courts. Carl Baar's essay 'Delays in the Administration of Justice' is a relatively smooth read, and shows the absence of a direct link between speedy justice and forms of government, and even resources. Baar's suggestion of a pilot Court or a 'best practices' court too is useful as a live experiment that would assist more innovative practices and methods of dealing with backlogs and faster disposition of cases. Arnab Kumar Hazra's and Maja B. Micevska's contribution uses econometric analysis to examine court congestion. While the econometrics part is a tad heavy for lay-readers (Sample - "All significance tests are two-sided asymptomatic t-tests that are consistent in the presence of heteroskadasticity"), their tests do reiterate some known facts, e.g. that civil cases run longer than criminal cases, and suggest that increasing the number of judges does not always solve the problem of court congestion as 'court productivity' itself is low, since courts are addressing newer-filed cases rather than the backlog. Barry Walsh's essay, 'Pursuing Best Practice Levels of Judicial Productivity - An International Perspective on Case Backlog and Delay Reduction in India' is arguably the highest point of this collection. It compares the court systems of Delhi (pop. 13.8 million) and Australia (pop. 20 million) and shows that not only does Australia have effectively twice the number of judges per million of population, but that an Australian judge disposes double the number of cases as compared to a judge in Delhi in a year. Walsh's analysis is that despite the colonial similarities, the case management and court management systems used in the countries are vastly different and account for this dramatic difference in judicial productivity. Walsh also correctly pinpoints the absence of settlements and a predominance of contested hearings; the large number of adjournments; and a lack of continuous trials as key factors that create delay. One of the major drawbacks of this collection is its inconsistent quality. Referencing and citation in the volume are often inadequate, reducing the usability of the collection. Further, while some contributions to the collection are well researched, others dawdle endlessly. Criminal justice system While most of the book completely ignores the criminal justice system, this receives attention in the paper, 'Crime Deterrence and the Need for Reforms: An analysis of Indian States' by Debashis Chakraborty, Arnab Kumar Hazra and Pavel Chakraborty. The authors use data from Crime in India (1954 - 2002) to show growth rate of crime. However they use only data of Indian Penal Code (IPC) crimes and ignore Special and Local Laws (SLL), suggesting that these cover largely minor offences. Unfortunately, this is not true; the authors forget that besides minor legislation even TADA and POTA were classified as SLL! Given the thousands over arrests that took place under POTA itself (instead of the IPC) in the late-nineties are not included in their data, their conclusion that the growth rate of 'crime' was below 1 per cent between 1999 and 2002 raises doubts. Other analysis too is poor: observing the fact that the number of prisons is inadequate, the authors conclude that the focus of government action is not on the severity of punishment. Arriving at such a conclusion in the absence of a study on punishment provided in new legislation passed raises doubts about its validity. More seriously, the diagnosis in the 'agendas for reform' set out by the authors in the essay is simply reproduced from the now-discredited Malimath report (MHA: 2003). The authors write, "The two major problems besieging the criminal justice system are huge pendency of criminal cases along with the inordinate delay in disposal of criminal cases on one hand and the low rate of conviction in cases involving serious crimes on the other." An identical paragraph can be found on Page 4 of the Malimath Report available on the Ministry's website. Plagiarism aside, it is the politics of the agenda for such reform that raises concern. This identification of reform priorities is not a careless act but a careful statement on what is deemed vital, and what is secondary. No surprise then that the focus is on delay and low convictions rather than the large number of undertrials in Indian prisons - who form between 66 to 70 per cent of the total prison population and are often underprivileged, from rural and agricultural backgrounds. (NCRB: 2006, NHRC: 2004) While it is argued that tackling delay eventually helps under-trials, a far more effective strategy would be to avoid unnecessary arrests altogether. In early November 2000 the Law Commission of India published a Consultation Paper on Law Relating to Arrest in which it cited the third Report of the National Police Commission which suggested that nearly 60 per cent of all arrests by the police were either unnecessary or unjustified. While the present authors do make a nominal reference to reducing arrests as part of 'police reform' (as opposed to 'judicial reform'), there is very little deliberation on the lack of use and misuse by judges of bail provisions. Certainly no empirical research is provided for the number of cases where persons are in jail either on bailable offences where judges refuse to release them on personal bond or because they could not afford the exorbitant bail conditions set by the Court despite a number of Supreme Court judgements to the contrary. A narrow lens There's little to recommend in this collection for the lay-reader. The obvious neo-liberal emphasis of the editors on 'growth rate' ensures that reform is seen only in the context of economic growth and in terms of tackling pendency of cases, while the fact that the Indian judiciary offers no hope for the vast majority of citizens is nowhere even raised. Even in tackling pendency, the essays barely go beyond 'improvement in infrastructure and court productivity'. With regard to criminal law the collection virtually pushes all issues of human rights and fair trial off the table, with its clear emphasis on 'increasing convictions' and 'speedier justice'. E.g. the references to judicial remand by 'video conferencing' do not even consider the dangers of such use of technology which effectively do away with the duty of the magistrate to check for custodial violence and reduce the entire safeguard to a mere formality. Similarly there is no thought given to the viability of plea-bargaining in the Indian context where the bulk of accused persons are illiterate, poor and therefore vulnerable to coercion by the police and prosecutors. The volume is perhaps most useful in highlighting what is referred to as "the cunning of judicial reform" - the use of the agenda of legal empowerment of the poor for state and corporate interest (Baxi, P: 2007). Given that one of the book's editors is Secretary General, Punjab Haryana and Delhi Chamber of Commerce and Industry, and the other is staff consultant to the Asian Development Bank for the India Administration of Justice Project (a project conducted jointly with the Government of India), and that a number of other authors were also associated with the same project, it is clear that this book represents views that are predominant within the corridors of power. A fuller analysis of judicial reforms, unburdened by this singular lens, is still awaited. ¨’ Bikram Jeet Batra 25 May 2007 Bikram Jeet Batra is a Delhi-based lawyer and presently visiting fellow at the Centre for Study of Law and Governance, Jawaharlal Nehru University, New Delhi. Judicial Reforms in India: Issues and Aspects, Ed: Arnab Kumar Hazra and Bibek Debroy, Academic Foundation with Rajiv Gandhi Institute for Contemporary Studies, New Delhi: 2007. Rs. 750 URL for this article: https://www.indiatogether.org/2007/may/rvw-judreform.htm
Judicial reform C Raja Mohan Posted online: Tuesday, April 10, 2007 at 0000 hrs IST As the Congress party and its Left allies pick an ill-considered fight with the judiciary, Communist China’s Chief Justice, Xiao Yang was in New Delhi last week to learn the tricks of distancing the court from the executive. Having once peddled the theory of “committed judiciary”, the Congress and the Left would love to subordinate the bench. China is moving in the other direction. As its economy grows more complex and the society more divisive, Chinese courts have acquired a new political weight. Although severely constrained by the Party-State, the Chinese Supreme Court is finding space for itself — from implementing a range of newly approved economic laws to reforming the criminal procedure code. Judge Xiao now has the huge task of interpreting the historic new law on property rights that was approved by the NPC last month. The law fudged a number of difficult issues to mollify the ideologues in the Chinese Communist Party. The Chinese chief justice wants to make sure that courts across the nation clearly understand the 247 Articles in the law, which proclaims, “the property of the state, the collective, the individual is protected by law, and no unit or individuals may infringe upon it”. Last year, Judge Xiao put an end to a 27-year-old practice in China where the lower courts decided on the death penalty. The Supreme Court has now reclaimed the authority to review and ratify all death sentences. The Supreme Court is empowered enough to crack down on judicial corruption and the failure of other state organs to implement the court’s orders. Meanwhile pressures are building from below for reforming various laws. Last month, about 30 members of the NPC introduced amendments to the criminal procedure code demanding greater legal protection of the basic rights of those charged with crimes and limiting the power of the state to extract confessions. Soft power Communist China’s new-found obsession with ‘soft power’ as an instrument of foreign policy continues. The latest exhortation comes from Liu Yunshan, politburo member and propaganda czar, who said, “The first two decades of this century are a strategic period for China’s cultural development, and we should seize this opportunity to greatly improve the country’s cultural soft power”. Meanwhile the Chinese government is raising the outlay on diplomatic spending abroad by nearly 40 per cent to 23 billion Yuan or nearly Rs 13,000 crore. Much of this spending abroad will go to such activities as foreign aid, peace-keeping operations and increased support to international organisations. Happy boy Soft power, of course, is a double-edged sword. While leveraging it abroad, China is aware of the need to manage it at home. As millions of Chinese youth gear up for the reality show, Happy Boy inspired by American Idol, the CCP is laying down the law. “No weirdness, no vulgarity, no low taste,” the state administration for Radio, Film and Television told Hunan Satellite company, the show’s promoter. The eleven restrictions laid down by the Chinese Censor Board include one that the contestants must only sing “healthy and ethically inspiring” songs. As reality shows gather massive viewership, the CCP is concerned about the potential political consequences. Last year, a similar show Super Girl drew nearly 400 million viewers to its finale. There was speculation that the CCP might ban Hunan Satellite from going ahead with its programme this year. It required the intervention of the party boss of Hunan, Mao Zedong’s province, to save the show. For the critics in Beijing, the reality shows threaten not just Chinese culture but also the CCP’s ideological dominance. For the Hunan government, the huge revenues from the show were too important to be subject to the ideological concerns about “spiritual pollution”. In a happy compromise, so typical of the Chinese pragmatism, Hunan Satellite agreed to modify the format of the programme. The show must go on. The writer is professor at the Rajaratnam School of International Studies, Singapore


CCI Pro

Leave a Reply

Your are not logged in . Please login to post replies

Click here to Login / Register